Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS), Marginal Utility (MU), and how they relate

academics economics
By Emily

In this post, I start off by explaining the Marginal Rate of Substitution (Sections II-IV). Then, I cover the concept of Marginal Utility (Sections V-VII). In both cases, I start with a story explanation, then give a formal definition, and finally provide some other useful information about the concept. After that, I connect the two concepts (Marginal Utility and Marginal Rate of Substitution) and show how they relate mathematically, first without calculus (Section VIII) and then with calculus (Section IX). Finally, I demonstrate that the Marginal Rate of Substitution has an advantage over Marginal Utility in terms of describing preferences and behavior (Section X), because it is less sensitive to the exact utility function you choose to use!

Story Explanation of the Marginal Rate of Substitution

Let’s imagine that I have some jelly beans and some M&Ms. I like both types of candy and I like having the choice between fruity and chocolatey, so I’m pretty happy right now. Now imagine someone comes along and wants one of my jelly beans. Maybe this person only wants half a jelly bean. The point is that the person wants a very very small amount of jelly beans.

If I give the person half a jelly bean, I’m a little less happy than I was before. But! The person could give me some amount of M&Ms that would make me exactly as happy as I was before I gave up that tiny bit of jelly beans. The amount of M&Ms that would make me exactly as happy might be one-third of an M&M, it might be two M&Ms, or maybe it would be half an M&M. The point is, a very small amount of M&Ms would make me equally as happy as I was before, and this amount of M&Ms is not necessarily equal to the amount of jelly beans I gave up.

The Marginal Rate of Substitution captures the rate at which I would be willing to exchange a tiny bit of jelly beans for M&Ms.

Formal Definition of the Marginal Rate of Substitution

The Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS) is the rate at which a consumer would be willing to give up a very small amount of good 2 (which we call x2) for some of good 1 (which we call x1) in order to be exactly as happy after the trade as before the trade.

Let x1 and x2 be very small changes (e.g. “marginal” changes) in x1 and x2. Then, the MRS equals x2 ÷ ∆x1. Note that the MRS is negative, because we are giving up some of x2 (so x2 is negative) to get some of x1 (so x1 is positive). A negative divided by a positive is a negative, so it follows that the MRS is negative.

Relationship Between the MRS and Indifference Curves

At any given point along an indifference curve, the MRS is the slope of the indifference curve at that point. Note that most indifference curves are actually curves, so their slopes are changing as you move along them. That means that the MRS is also changing!

To find the slope of a curve at a specific point, you use calculus. Take the first derivative of the equation for the indifference curve, then plug in the values of x1 and x2 for the point you are interested in. That will give you the MRS at that point.

What do you think happens to the MRS along the indifference curve? When I have a lot of x2, I’m willing to give up quite a bit of x2 to get a little bit of x1. However, this changes as I move along my indifference curve. When I get to a point where I’m just as happy as before but now I have tons of x1 and almost no x2, I no longer want to give up much x2 to get a little x1. This phenomenon is known as the diminishing rate of marginal substitution.

The Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS) is the slope of the indifference curve

blog1

Story Explanation of the Marginal Utility

Let’s imagine again that I have some jelly beans and some M&Ms. If someone takes a tiny (“marginal”) amount of jelly beans away from me, I’m slightly less happy. Similarly, if someone gives me a tiny bit more jelly beans, I’m a little happier. My marginal utility of jelly beans is the change in happiness I experience from a tiny (e.g. “marginal”) change in the amount of jelly beans I have.

Similarly, my happiness (which economists call “utility”) would change if someone changed the amount of M&Ms I had. When the change in M&Ms is tiny (“marginal”) then the resulting change in my utility is known as my marginal utility of M&Ms.

Note that in both cases, marginal utility is defined with respect to a specific type of candy that I have. We considered the marginal utility of jelly beans and the marginal utility of M&Ms. We can combine these ideas to figure out what would happen if I experienced simultaneous changes in the amount of jelly beans and M&Ms in my possession, but marginal utility is always defined with respect to a specific good. 

Formal Definition of Marginal Utility

The marginal utility with respect to good 1 is the change in utility a consumer experiences when the amount of x1 the consumer has changes by a tiny bit while the amount of x2 the consumer has remains constant. We can represent this marginal utility as:

Screen Shot 2017-02-03 at 2.41.16 PM.png

Here, MU1 is the rate of change in utility (U) resulting from a small change in good 1 (x1).

Similarly, the marginal utility with respect to good 2 is the rate at which utility changes when the consumer’s amount of x2 is changed by a marginal amount while his/her amount of x1 remains fixed at a constant amount. The equation for MU2 is:

Screen Shot 2017-02-03 at 2.45.06 PM.png.

Marginal utility will always be positive when we are dealing with goods (as opposed to bads or neutrals). This is because getting more will make us happier, so when the denominator (x1) is positive, the numerator (U) is also positive. Similarly, when we lose some of good 1, x1 is negative and we are less happy, so U is also negative. A negative divided by a negative is positive, so the marginal utility of a good will always be a positive value.

Marginal Utility v. Actual Change in Utility

Note that in both cases, we can do a little algebra to find the total change in utility resulting from a marginal change in one good while the amount of the other good is held constant.

Let’s use good 1 as our example. Above, we saw this:

Screen Shot 2017-02-03 at 3.54.29 PM.png

If we multiply both sides by x1, we then have:

Screen Shot 2017-02-03 at 3.55.25 PM.png

Therefore, the change in utility resulting from a tiny change in good 1 and no change in good 2 is just the product of that tiny change in good 1 and the marginal utility with respect to good 1.

Connection Between Marginal Utility & Marginal Rate of Substitution

The Marginal Rate of Substitution looks at the balance in changes of good 1 and good 2 required for the consumer to be indifferent between his/her consumption bundles before and after trade. But what does indifference mean? It means that utility for both bundles is exactly equal. Therefore, Screen Shot 2017-02-03 at 3.56.34 PM.png

There is some (negative) change in utility resulting from giving up a little bit of good 2, and as we saw in the previous section, this change equals Screen Shot 2017-02-03 at 3.57.52 PM.png

Similarly, there is some (positive) change in utility from getting a little more of good 1, which equals:

Screen Shot 2017-02-03 at 3.58.40 PM.png

Since we want to be indifferent before and after the trade, it must be that the sum of these changes equals zero. Our equation would thus look like this:

Screen Shot 2017-02-03 at 3.59.57 PM.png

With a little algebra, we can find the MRS from this equation of marginal utilities!

First, when we subtract MU1x1 from both sides, we are left with the following, Screen Shot 2017-02-03 at 5.23.55 PM.png

Next, divide both sides by x1 and MU2. The result is

Screen Shot 2017-02-03 at 5.26.06 PM.png

The left hand side is just the MRS, and the right hand side is the negative ratio of marginal utilities. In the MRS section, we learned why the left hand side would automatically be negative. The right hand side needs the negative sign because marginal utility is positive for goods, so the ratio of marginal utilities is always positive.

MRS and Marginal Utility Relationship:  Calculus Edition

When using calculus, the marginal utility of good 1 is defined by the partial derivative of the utility function with respect to x1. That is:Screen Shot 2017-02-03 at 5.27.43 PM.png

We want to consider a tiny change in our consumption bundle, and we represent this change as(dx1, dx2). We want the change to be such that our utility does not change (e.g. du = 0). Therefore, we want to solve:Screen Shot 2017-02-03 at 5.30.22 PM.png

Rearranging terms as before, we find this:

Screen Shot 2017-02-03 at 5.31.24 PM.png

The equation above is just the calculus version of this:

Screen Shot 2017-02-03 at 5.32.35 PM.png

Instead of using derivatives, we could use implicit functions. Any given indifference curve can be represented as

Screen Shot 2017-02-03 at 5.33.43 PM.png 

where k is a constant and the level of utility held constant along the indifference curve. We use the notation x2(x1) simply to illustrate that x2 is a function of x1.

If we differentiate both sides of the equation with respect to x1, we get: Screen Shot 2017-02-03 at 5.38.57 PM.png

We can again rearrange terms and the result is the same as what we found before:

Screen Shot 2017-02-03 at 5.39.50 PM.png

Monotonic Transformations Affect MU but Not MRS

The downside of marginal utility is that its magnitude depends on the utility function we’re using. This is not ideal, because utility functions are usually ordinal, which means we don’t care exactly what numbers the utility function spits out, we just care that the utility function gives us higher numbers for bundles the consumer likes better.

The great thing about the MRS is that even though it is function of the marginal utilities with respect to goods 1 and 2, it doesn’t change if apply a positive monotonic transformation to our utility function. (Positive monotonic transformations are any functions that preserve the original order when applied, like adding a constant to the original utility function, raising the original utility function to an odd power, taking the natural log, etc.) To see why this is so, let’s pretend u(x1,x2) was our original utility function and is our monotonically transformed utility function (so ƒ(u) is a monotonic function). Then, using our calculus definition of the MRS, we have the following before the transformation:

Screen Shot 2017-02-03 at 5.46.41 PM.png

After the transformation, we have:


Screen Shot 2017-02-03 at 5.47.23 PM.png

So the MRS is completely unchanged by any monotonic transformation!

Acknowledgments: much of this post was inspired by chapters 3 and 4 of Hal Varian’s textbook Intermediate Microeconomics: A Modern Approach.

Comments

topicTopics
academics study skills MCAT medical school admissions SAT expository writing college admissions English MD/PhD admissions strategy writing LSAT GMAT GRE physics chemistry math biology graduate admissions academic advice ACT interview prep law school admissions test anxiety language learning premed MBA admissions career advice personal statements homework help AP exams creative writing MD study schedules computer science test prep Common Application summer activities history mathematics philosophy organic chemistry secondary applications economics supplements research 1L PSAT admissions coaching grammar law psychology statistics & probability legal studies ESL CARS SSAT covid-19 dental admissions logic games reading comprehension engineering USMLE calculus PhD admissions Spanish mentorship parents Latin biochemistry case coaching verbal reasoning DAT English literature STEM excel medical school political science skills AMCAS French Linguistics MBA coursework Tutoring Approaches academic integrity chinese letters of recommendation Anki DO Social Advocacy admissions advice algebra artificial intelligence astrophysics business cell biology classics diversity statement gap year genetics geometry kinematics linear algebra mechanical engineering mental health presentations quantitative reasoning study abroad technical interviews time management work and activities 2L DMD IB exams ISEE MD/PhD programs Sentence Correction adjusting to college algorithms amino acids analysis essay art history athletics business skills careers cold emails data science dental school finance first generation student functions information sessions international students internships logic networking poetry resume revising science social sciences software engineering tech industry trigonometry writer's block 3L AAMC Academic Interest EMT FlexMed Fourier Series Greek Health Professional Shortage Area Italian Lagrange multipliers London MD vs PhD MMI Montessori National Health Service Corps Pythagorean Theorem Python Shakespeare Step 2 TMDSAS Taylor Series Truss Analysis Zoom acids and bases active learning architecture argumentative writing art art and design schools art portfolios bacteriology bibliographies biomedicine brain teaser campus visits cantonese capacitors capital markets central limit theorem centrifugal force chemical engineering chess chromatography class participation climate change clinical experience community service constitutional law consulting cover letters curriculum dementia demonstrated interest dimensional analysis distance learning econometrics electric engineering electricity and magnetism escape velocity evolution executive function freewriting genomics graphing harmonics health policy history of medicine history of science hybrid vehicles hydrophobic effect ideal gas law immunology induction infinite institutional actions integrated reasoning intermolecular forces intern investing investment banking lab reports linear maps mandarin chinese matrices mba medical physics meiosis microeconomics mitosis mnemonics music music theory nervous system neurology neuroscience object-oriented programming office hours operating systems